What Does Economics Tell Us About Early Childhood Policy?
Research SummaryPublished May 8, 2008
Research SummaryPublished May 8, 2008
Advances in neuroscience, developmental psychology, and program evaluation have been combined to develop a unified framework that provides evidence-based guidance related to early childhood policy. This research shows how insights from the field of economics—human capital theory and monetary payoffs—also contribute to that framework.
An increasing chorus of Fortune 500 CEOs, Federal Reserve Bank analysts, Nobel Prize-winning economists, and other business and economic leaders have led the call to increase public "investments" in early childhood. This call is driven by research findings that increasingly emphasize the importance of laying a strong foundation in early childhood and that show that a range of early interventions can successfully put children on the path toward positive development, preventing poor outcomes in adulthood. These findings—along with increasing recognition in the public-health and social-service sectors that providing program services in early childhood has benefits over treatment later in life—have contributed to the evolution of economists' support for early childhood investments.
To help decisionmakers in the public and private sectors, service providers, and the public more generally, RAND researchers drew on their decades-long expertise in applying economics to early childhood issues to demonstrate how two economic concepts—human capital theory and monetary payoffs—contribute to a unifying framework that provides evidence-based guidance for early childhood policy. These concepts are summarized in this research brief.
An economic model known as human capital theory is a useful, unifying framework that encompasses many of the disparate threads of current thinking about early childhood policy: that later skills build on earlier skills; development occurs over multiple stages; human development involves the interaction of nature and nurture; and human capital, skills, and capabilities involve multiple dimensions.
The fundamental insight is that human capital theory provides a simple framework that is consistent with observations about skill formation and helps us predict how various policies would be likely to affect skill formation.
A few examples highlight how predictions of human capital theory are consistent with patterns documented in the program evaluation literature:
Human capital theory implies that "investments" in the productive capacities of individuals can improve individual outcomes and that these investments might produce the greatest payoffs when made early in individuals' lives. Characterizing the development of human potential as a production process with parallels to other outlays of money and time that would produce returns in the future helps motivate the analysis of the "monetary payoffs" of early childhood programs.
Perhaps the most widely recognized intersection between economics and early childhood policy is the analysis of the costs and benefits of early childhood programs and related analyses that describe the rate of return on investments in early childhood programs.
The fundamental insight of economics is manifested in a growing body of program evaluations that shows that early childhood programs can generate government savings that more than repay their costs and produce returns to society that outpace most public and private investments.
Table 1 illustrates various child outcomes that may be affected by early childhood programs and the associated monetary savings (or costs) to government (i.e., taxpayers). In addition to the effects on government spending or revenue, the program benefits may also generate private benefits to program participants or other members of society. For example, as shown, increased labor force participation and earnings in adulthood benefit the government by yielding increased tax revenue, but the increased earnings (net of taxes) are also a benefit to the program participant.
Effect on Child Outcome | Monetary Benefits (or Costs) to Government |
---|---|
Reduced child maltreatment | Lower costs to child welfare system |
Reduced child accidents and injuries | Lower costs for emergency room visits and other public health care costs |
Reduced incidence of teen childbearing | Lower costs for public health care system and social welfare programs |
Reduced grade repetition | Fewer years spent in K–12 education |
Reduced use of special education | Lower costs for special education |
Increased high school graduation rate | (More years spent in K–12 education, i.e., drop-out rate reduced) |
Increased college attendance rate | (More years spent in postsecondary education) |
Increased labor force participation and earnings in adulthood | Increased tax revenue |
Reduced use of welfare and other means-tested programs | Reduced administrative costs for social welfare programs; reduced welfare-program transfer payments |
Reduced crime and contact with criminal justice system | Lower costs for the criminal justice system |
Reduced incidence of smoking and substance abuse | Lower costs for public health care system and from premature death |
Improved pregnancy outcomes | Lower medical costs from fewer low birth weight babies |
SOURCE: Adapted from Lynn A. Karoly, M. Rebecca Kilburn, and Jill S. Cannon, Early Childhood Interventions: Proven Results, Future Promise, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation, MG-341-PNC, 2005, Table 4.1. (Full Document)
In terms of assessing the costs and benefits of early childhood programs, Table 2 summarizes the results of earlier RAND research that examined nine early childhood programs or groups of programs, including programs that provide parent education or home visiting and those that combined parent education or home visiting with early childhood education.
Table 2 shows the age at last follow-up for each program, followed by data on program costs, total program benefits, and net program benefits (benefits minus costs). The final column shows the benefit-cost ratio for each program, calculated by dividing total program benefits by program costs. Thus, for example, the benefit-cost ratio for Home Instruction for Parents of Preschool Youngsters (HIPPY) USA is 1.80 ($3,032/$1,681); this means that the program generates a benefit of $1.80 for each dollar invested in the program.
Program | Age at Last Follow-up | Program Costs ($) | Total Benefits to Society ($) | Net Benefits ($) | Benefit-Cost Ratio |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Comprehensive Child Development Program (CCDP): Case managers provide coordinated services to low-income families with children under 5 | 5 | 37,388 | -9 | -37,397 | — |
HIPPY USA Paraprofessionals provide home visits to disadvantaged families with children ages 3–5 | 6 | 1,681 | 3,032 | 1,351 | 1.80 |
Infant Health and Development Program (IHDP): Home visiting and center-based child development program for low birth weight babies from birth to age 3 | 8 | 49,021 | 0 | -49,021 | — |
Nurse-Family Partnership Public-health nurses provide home visits to low-income first-time mothers from prenatal period to age 2 | 15 | 9,118 | 26,298 | 17,180 | 2.88 |
Home visiting for at-risk mothers and children (meta-analysis): Average effect across 13 home visiting programs | Varies | 4,892 | 10,969 | 6,077 | 2.24 |
Abecedarian Program: Comprehensive, center-based child development program for at-risk children from infancy to age 5 | 21 | 42,871 | 138,635 | 95,764 | 3.23 |
Chicago CPC: Center-based, one- or two-year part-day academic-year preschool program with parent participation | 21 | 6,913 | 49,337 | 42,424 | 7.14 |
High/Scope Perry Preschool Project: Center-based, one- or two-year part-day academic-year preschool program with home visiting | 40 | 14,830 | 253,154 | 238,324 | 17.07 |
Early childhood education for low-income 3- and 4-year-olds (meta-analysis): Average effect across 48 preschool programs | Varies | 6,681 | 15,742 | 9,061 | 2.36 |
SOURCE: Adapted from Karoly, Kilburn, and Cannon (2005, Table 4.4).
NOTE: All dollar values are 2003 dollars per child and reflect the present value of amounts over time, where future values are discounted to age 0 of the participating child, using a 3 percent annual real discount rate.
This analysis shows, first, that early childhood programs can produce benefits that offset their costs but that not every early childhood program does so. Seven of the nine analyses found benefit-cost ratios greater than 1, implying that the benefits outweighed the costs, with a range between $2 and $17 in benefits for every dollar invested. However, even for those programs with positive net benefits to society as a whole, when viewed from the government's perspective, not all programs generate net savings sufficient to offset a full public sector investment in program delivery. Future research needs to identify the features of cost-effective programs.
Second, some of the variation in benefit-cost ratios results from differences in the length of follow-up for the program evaluations and the range of outcomes measured in the evaluations. Higher benefit-cost ratios are associated with programs that have the longest follow-up, such as the Perry Preschool Project, which has followed a group of participants to age 40. The lack of positive net benefits for two of the programs is because there were no significant improvements in the outcomes measured (CCDP) or because the favorable effects were for outcomes that could not readily be expressed in dollar terms (IHDP).
Third, the findings show that a spectrum of program types generated payoffs: small-scale, model programs and larger-scale programs that have been implemented for several decades; very expensive and intensive programs and less expensive ones; and early education programs (i.e., center-based preschool programs) and home visiting ones.
Fourth, there is evidence that returns from early childhood programs decline under certain conditions. For example, while monetary payoffs may still be positive for universal programs, the rate of return may be higher when programs are targeted toward the groups likely to benefit from them most.
There is a growing recognition that reaping the monetary payoffs of early childhood services is tied to the quality of those services. However, although raising the quality of early childhood services in the public or private sector may be appealing to policymakers, features associated with higher quality almost always require more resources. So with no increase in funding, a shift toward higher quality may entail a reduction in services offered.
Thus, the fundamental insight of economics in discussing early childhood-program quality is that there is generally a quality-quantity trade-off in early childhood services unless budget outlays grow.
Given the need to allocate scarce resources, how can policymakers decide who should benefit from their policies? Should they choose families or taxpayers, for example? And there is also the question of whether the policy time frame should be short or long.
Given those considerations, the field of economics also contributes by showing that alternative decisionmaking rules can help when allocating resources:
Economics does not value one of these approaches over another; instead, it provides a framework for selecting optimal service levels given that a community has established its goals and priorities in the early childhood field.
The fundamental insight from economics is that efficient early childhood policy would include a spectrum of services rather than one "best" approach, and economic theory also provides some guidance about how to choose an optimal level of each type of service or program given the total budget available for all services.
The efficient portfolio of early childhood services provides the greatest total benefits to the community. Economists would urge policymakers to fund each program or service up to the point at which the last person served by each is generating a similar net benefit. This is true because, if programs were funded at other levels, the total benefits to society could be raised by providing fewer services to families in the program that provided the lower marginal net benefits and more services to families in the program that provided the higher marginal net benefits.
A common theme that emerges from economic theory and analysis and from other disciplines is the crucial role that early experiences play in laying a foundation for ongoing development and the fact that development is a multiperiod process, with outcomes in each period building on those of the previous period. Both on theoretical grounds and given findings from empirical analyses—including cost-benefit analysis—economic research promotes a reorientation of child and human services toward investment and prevention and away from attempting to "treat" poor outcomes that manifest themselves later in the life cycle. Implementing such an approach would require fundamentally rethinking how nearly every human service is delivered. Shifting toward a paradigm in which resources are invested in early human capital might produce better outcomes, save taxpayers money, and improve the quality of life for the people in whom we invest.
This publication is part of the RAND research brief series. Research briefs present policy-oriented summaries of individual published, peer-reviewed documents or of a body of published work.
This document and trademark(s) contained herein are protected by law. This representation of RAND intellectual property is provided for noncommercial use only. Unauthorized posting of this publication online is prohibited; linking directly to this product page is encouraged. Permission is required from RAND to reproduce, or reuse in another form, any of its research documents for commercial purposes. For information on reprint and reuse permissions, please visit www.rand.org/pubs/permissions.
RAND is a nonprofit institution that helps improve policy and decisionmaking through research and analysis. RAND's publications do not necessarily reflect the opinions of its research clients and sponsors.